РефератыИностранный языкTaTaxation In Japan Essay Research Paper The

Taxation In Japan Essay Research Paper The

Taxation In Japan Essay, Research Paper


The role of taxation in the transformation of the Japanese


Economy Introduction Before the Meiji restoration under the


feudal Tokugawa Shogunate, taxation was mainly a tool for


warfare and military power. The system was highly


regressive and pressed lightly on the rich and profit-earners.


It was calculated to preserve a very unequal distribution on


incomes and to stimulate the accumulation of private capital.


This tendency somehow continued and was magnified before


W.W.II when direct taxation was introduced for a more


equal and balanced system. However, the Meiji restoration


did bring with it tremendous changes to the tax system and


the use of the revenues. The Japanese government has since


had an active participation in the economy, yet not


controlling it directly but rather through market mechanisms.


It took responsibility for promoting economic growth by


using incentives and taxes collected in an effective way. The


often cited goal of taxation in western countries that was


equality was often sacrificed for the goal of economic growth


in order to prevent being colonized, then to pursuit the desire


to become an imperialist nation and then for pride and


export. The role of government and its fiscal policies played


an important role in the transformation of the Japanese


economy through the periods of Meiji restoration, before


W.W.II and post W.W.II period where taxes respectively


shifted from land taxes to internal indirect taxes to income /


direct taxes. (Fig 1) Period of Meiji Restoration During the


first years of the Meiji reforms, the government had serious


financial difficulties with tax revenues inadequate for its


massive commitments. In 1873, land reforms gave tittles to


landowners and customary tenants, freed the transfer and


sale of land from feudal restrictions and imposed tax


obligations equal to 3 per cent (which was lowered to 2.5%


in 1878) of the value of land. In addition a 30% local surtax


was imposed on the land taxes. These heavy land taxes were


used to provide monetary compensations to the old ruling


class for the termination of their feudal incomes in kind and


to finance the new administration which introduced new


education and to support its military. The agricultural sector,


and in fact the peasants, therefore bore the great bulk of the


cost to Japan’s modernization. The land taxes contributed to


over 70% of the central government’s revenue during the first


decade of the Restoration. Since the capital needs of


agriculture were small even after the landlords devotion to


the improvement of agricultural techniques and introduction


of winter drainage, the increasing savings and surplus of


landlords were transferred out of the primary sector into


other sectors. The fiscal system as a whole was heavy in


absolute terms yet highly regressive. The burden was


constantly on the agriculture sector, even when


non-agricultural sectors were growing at a phenomenal rate.


As seen in Figure 1, under indirect taxes, before the turn of


the century, the excise taxes played a prominent yet second


to land taxes at about 20% of the government’s total


revenue. These included taxes on soya, sugar, textiles and


government monopoly profits in tobacco, camphor and salt.


The combined effect of the land taxes and consumption


taxes was heavy taxes on both peasant and consumer and a


lighter burden for the landlord and industrial-merchant


classes. The income tax did not appear until 1887 and the


business tax which was the corporate tax did not come into


effect until 1896 and at a low flat rate of 3%. The result was


the subsidizing of the manufacturing and service sector at the


expense of the primary sector. To strengthen the incentives


for reinvestment and accumulation of productive wealth was


strengthened by the absence of inheritance and real estate


taxes before 1905 and a relatively low rate thereafter. The


role of the family and the firm that existed also as a closely


bound unit also made the saving, transferring form generation


to generation and development favorable. Therefore, the


Zaibatsus, the conglomerate oligopolies could charge


monopoly prices and concentrate on exports. At this time,


between the 1870-1900, there was the traditional export


expansion of silk and other produces, coupled with mild


primary import substitution. Tariffs and revenue on foreign


trade were also low at the time due to the fact that the


Japanese government was under the influence of foreign


countries and autonomy of tariffs was not until 1899.


However, this tradition had little change even after the


gradual regaining of autonomy. This was a very different


from the path followed by other developing countries which


usually place heavy taxes on trade because they are the


simplest and easiest form of taxation. Japan, by not following


the easy path and concentrating on export substitution and


land taxes for internal revenue creating a thriving export of


primary goods before the 1920s. Period before W.W.II The


era of the land taxes ended in 1908 and was followed by


indirect taxes, mainly on alcoholic beverages and tobacco. It


was not until 1935 that income taxes on individuals and


corporations became the most important source of total


revenues. The modern tax form only took form in the 1940


to prepare for the wartime economy, the whole tax system


was thoroughly overhauled to base on direct taxes. The


individual tax was a scheduler tax, under which different


sources of income were levied by different tax rates. It was


supplemented by a progressive comprehensive tax which


applied to an individual’s aggregated income above a specific


amount. On the other hand, the corporate income tax was


imposed on corporate income at a flat rate of 18%. The


commodity tax was introduced in 1937 mainly to collect


revenue for wartime expenses, and the tax on alcoholic


beverage was also simplified in 1940. The relative share of


indirect taxes fell as a result of the tax reforms. The 1940


reform also separated the personal income tax from


corporate income tax. This period saw the rise of the power


of the military in the government and influence after the


winning wars of the Sino-Japaneses and Russia-Japanese


earlier in the century and the ailing and corruption of the


civilian government. The government was engaged in


continuous military activities and was penalized with


increased tariffs. However, due to expansion of its own


empire and influence which included Taiwan and Korea,


export suffered little and actually had a 70% increase in


volume between 1929 and 1937. This period also saw


heavy taxes and direct investment of government in industries


resulting in rapid growth of war related industries. This


period ended with the GNP declining from 1939 and 1944.


The tax system became the tool for direct financing in this


period. The military drove the economy and accounted for


27.98% of GNP by the second world war which could be


said as the grand continuation of the feudal Tokugawa


Shogunate military expansion policies. Post W.W.II With the


occupation forces lead by the United States taking over the


government, reforms were held on all aspects of the


government. Immediately after the war, the scheduler tax on


individual income was replaced by a unified tax on an


aggregate basis with graduated tax rates. In order to collect


necessary revenues, a 1% turnover tax was levied on the


basis of the sales amount at every stage of transaction. As


for the long term tax system design, it was also based on the


US system but was also an experimental ground for the


Shoup Mission which was a pioneer in many aspects of the


direct tax. The Shoup reform in 1949 was not the first


reform after the war to the chaotic after-war tax system, but


it has had the most lasting effect on the development of the


Japanese economy. The Shops Report tried to build a


progressive direct tax based tax system with local autonomy


and simplicity that would be permanent and stable. Indirect


taxes were not recommended due to the inequality among


the tax payers, dull the sense of civic responsibility and make


local governments uneasy. However, the Japanese


government regained autonomy during the Korean war and


made modifications such as the resuming taxation at the


national level and sacrificing equity which Shops put at the


utmost priority for convenience of efficiency and


administration. The burden on firms, especially big business


was lowered. This was to give priority to the restoration of


the postwar economy and the promotion of capital


accumulation. Capital gains tax was abolished, under the


missions guidelines and this had a effect of the promotion of


capital accumulation as a national goal. Although partially


successful, the Shoup plan broke away from the military


roots of the Japanese tax system and engaged in a


responsive tax system which was in touch with the economy.


The four major taxes, income, corporate, accession and


consumption taxes all varied to different degrees from the


Shops Mission. However, the four taxes have been


remarkably stable in structure since 1950. The global income


tax system proposed by Shops was modified to a


combination of a comprehensive tax and a scheduler tax.


Instead of aggregating most incomes with progressive tax


rates, some incomes such as capital gains or interest income


were now subject to income taxation or were taxed at


reduced flat rates, separate from other incomes. These tax


concessions were intended to stimulate savings and income


and to improve the welfare level among specific taxpayers.


As for corporate income taxes, a split-rate system rather


than a uniform one in which a single rate is imposed on a


whole corporate income. This was similar to the one used in


West Germany in which retained profits and dividends were


taxed at different rates. Numerous tax measures have made


the corporate income tax extraordinarily complicated. As for


the accession tax on transfer of wealth proposed by Shops


Mission was replaced by a combination of inheritance and


gift taxes. Consumption taxes, in contrast to the general


modification of direct taxes remained unchanged since the


Shops Mission and there has been no general consumption


tax in Japan until April 1989. Therefore, Japan depends its


revenue from taxes on income and corporate income taxes,


which is the highest among OECD countries. Social security


contributions which are equivalent to payroll taxes also play


an equally important role in the raising of taxes. Japan is also


the only advanced country that does not impose a general


consumption tax. In 1985, of the total tax revenues collected


in Japan, 45.8% came from individuals and corporate


income taxes, 30.2% from social security contributions, 14%


from taxes on goods and services, 8.6% from property tax


and 1.1% from inheritance and gift taxes. Before the 1973


oil shock, the government engaged in a tax system with


incentives to promote exports, private savings and


investment, housing and technological development to


promote economic growth. These measures were included in


the Special Tax Measures Law and was formulated to


prepare a list of most of the incentive provisions applying


mainly to individual and corporate income taxes. As seen in


Figure 2 and Table 1, the corporate revenue lost to these


special tax measures but declined in importance after the mid


-1970s. The special tax measures was around 12.6 and


13.2% of total income tax revenues in the late 1950s fell to


8-9% in 1961-1962 then rose to 12% in 1965 and then


gradually declined to 5.0% in the early 1980s. The special


measures could be classified into tax exemptions and credits


and tax deferrals like accelerated depreciation and tax-free


reserves. These exemptions targeted specific industries such


as steel and machinery and also developing technological


innovation. The six main objectives of the tax incentives are


outlined the Ministry of Finance (MOF) as promotion of


saving; promotion of environmental quality and regional


development, promotion of natural resources, promotion of


technological development and modernization of industrial


equipment, strengthening of the financial position of firms and


other incentives. As seen in Table 2, the greatest decline in


importance is promotion of export and foreign investment


which included special deductions of export income from


taxation and accelerated depreciation for export orientated


firms. However, this is still an understatement of the


magnitude of tax incentives due to hidden incentives that are


not included by the MOF in special tax incentives. Firstly,


there is the provision for capital gains, interest and dividends


as part of the basic income tax law. Second, the


fractionation of individual income tax into separate classified


taxes loses a great deal of revenue and greatly reduces the


progressivity of the nominal rate structure, particularly at the


top brackets. Third, business expenses as special


depreciation accounting and deduction for part of social and


entertainment expenses are also not included. Fourth,


housing subsidy and low interest loans to executives are not


regarded as special tax measure. Fifth, the official estimate of


revenue is constantly low, so therefore, the special tax


measures are estimated low. Another feature of the Japanese


growth economy was the annual tax-cutting policy due to the


fact that GNP rose by an average of 15% a year between


1950 and 1960. The reason for the annual cuts were due to


the fact that Japan had a highly elastic income tax reaching


2.0 in the 1960s meaning that for every 10% growth in GDP


that would be a 20% growth in revenue. The Japanese


government did not use the money in the expansion of


<
p>government or counter-cyclical to obtain stable growth.


Social welfare was also limited for the insistence on


investment into growth and export. The tax cutting policy is


to keep the revenues to national income constant at around


20%. This was maintained between 1955 to 1965. This was


targeted at the individual income tax while both corporate


income tax and indirect taxes showed varying changes over


time. Corporate taxes increased much more frequently while


indirect taxes were raised to adjusted for the rise in


commodity prices. The result of the tax cutting and keeping a


lid on the growth of the public sector coupled by the lowest


expense on defense in the developed country was the lowest


tax rates in the developed country. Therefore, this permitted


the rapid increase in private demand. As mentioned above,


the tax system stresses simplicity instead of equity with the


result of benefiting business and professionals rather than the


employee. First, the Shops Mission suggested the "blue


return" system which is a self-assessment income tax for


small to medium size businesses. The benefits of the blue


return include basic deduction for blue return, special


deductions for wages of family members working in the


same company, and special tax-tree reserves for employees’


retirements, allowance for bad debt etc. These special


treatments reduce the tax burden of the family small business


firms. Secondly, there is the issue of withholding tax system


for wage and salary incomes. More than 80% of individual


income tax is withheld at the source. Although withholding is


applied to interest, dividend, and other income, the largest


portion of withheld taxes relate to employment income. As


seen in Figure 3, the income of salary earners is almost fully


identified by tax authorities while self-employed and farmers


have much an advantage in taxable income. This is often


referred as the "ku-ro-yon", 9-6-4 ratio of salaried workers,


self-employed and farmers. The third issue is the anonymous


and fictitious accounts. Banks accounts could be opened


with seals rather than signatures and banks make no attempt


to identify the seals. By creating a number of these tax-free


treatments, the wealthy was able to abuse the system.


Therefore, although the tax system structure was not


prominently regressive, the legislative side make the


wage-earners pay a higher price of taxation for the reason of


simplicity to businesses as proposed by the government. Tax


Structure and Economic Development In the period since


the Meiji Restoration, there has been government transfer


and tax incentive from the peasant and wage earners to


business to stimulate growth. Japan has had phenomenal


growth in the past hundred years, however, the question is


that if there is a direct relationship between tax structure and


economic development. In Table 3, y/N stands for per


capita real GNP with N as the total population, Ag/Y is the


agricultural products’ share in GNP with Ag as the output of


the primary sector, M/Y or (M+X)/Y as the openness of the


economy where M and X stand for import and export


respectively. As seen in Table 3, there is a significant


correlation between y/N, Ag/Y and T/Y between


1885-1944. Before the war, the agriculture sector still


played an important role in taxation structure. This is often


referred to as the dual sector and where the taxes in the form


of land taxes were charged heavily in taxation. There is also


no correlation between the postwar period of 1951-86 but


y/N and T/Y are still significantly related. As from


1951-1986, openness provides a better index than the other


two variables mentioned 25 years before the prewar period,


and it becomes even more significant in explaining T/Y for


the postwar period. Therefore, there is a correlation


between the openness of the economy, which is imports and


exports and the taxation structure. However, one could


emphasize the passive nature of the evolving tax system , in


which one could even say that the major determinant of tax


structure change is the structural change in the economy itself


during the process of economic development. When we


consider Table 4, where Tl is land taxes, Ti is indirect taxes,


and Ty income taxes on individual and corporate income. It


shows the relationship (R2)that land taxes made up the


principal shares revenue in 1885-1898 while indirect taxes


made up 1899-1935 and incomes taxes from 1936-86. This


proves the time division as mentioned above. However,


more importantly, as y/N increases, Tl/Tn and Ti/Tn


decreases. The relative importance of land and indirect taxes


faded when growth increased. As for the openness (M/Y or


(M+X)/Y) can be explained from the opposite signs in Ti/Tn


before and after the war (3.101 to -1.808). The negative


correlation after the war showed that openness was no


longer effective in increasing the indirect tax base at this level


of economic development and that the declining importance


of indirect taxes happen to have a close bearing with the


openness in a growing economy. That leaves us with Ty/Tn


dominantly affected by y/N, with the relative share of income


taxes rising in the course of development. The supply-side


point of view emphasizes the link between savings and


investment with I=S+(T-G) with net export as zero. As taxes


revenue were greater than government expenditures before


1975, investment from saving could be maximized. With net


exports as positive, it would also help on investment in the


country. As seen in Table 5, there was constant government


surplus before 1975. Therefore, it was only 1975, that the


government could continue the role using taxes to promote


investment and growth. As deficit grew, it would eat into the


savings and therefore investment. This was also the


tax-cutting policy which was before 1975 to prevent the


overburden of the tax payer with their high elasticity of


personal tax revenue. The growth can be shown using the


formula k=sx-(n+d)k which means for an increase in capital


stock savings has to be larger than depreciation. The


Japanese government promoted savings through tax cuts and


tax incentives and also allowed increased depreciation under


tax laws more rapid growth. Studies of the impact of the


special tax measures on Japanese economic growth are, for


the most part, inconclusive. There is virtually no relation


between the special tax measure to promote household


savings and the rate of private savings. Many of the special


tax measure were used in industries that were not regarded


as strategic from the standpoint of growth, such as the textile


industry which received favorable treatment but grew


relatively slowly. As mentioned above, though, the initial


depreciation allowances were used widely for expansion and


modernization in such strategic industries as steel and


machinery. Therefore, except for the stimulus in these


industries, the special tax measure did not have a substantial


effect on investment and growth. Although the tax system


and its effect on the economy is inconclusive, tax system may


affect economic activity in several ways. First, fro business


and managerial incentives, the regular salary earners with tax


withholding has a fully taxable income. As for the business


innovator and risk taker, the rewards are scarcely taxed by


the tax system which permits the tax-free accumulation of


capital gains and requires only modest tax payments on other


property incomes. As for management incentive, the typical


manager obtains his satisfaction through prestige of job,


expense of account which is often easily deductible under tax


laws. Implicit tax exemption fro unrealized capital gains


derived from undistributed corporate earnings permit the


manager to accumulate large amount of corporate wealth.


Second, the effect on economic stability, Japan with its high


elasticity on income taxation could be used for the stabilizing


effect of the economy to cushion the economic bumps.


However, the Japanese government has reduced the tax rate


and used monetary policy for short-run stabilization. As for


the effects on saving and investment, gross savings increased


from about 25% of GNP in the mid-1950s to about 40% in


the 1970s. Increase of the stock of capital is important for


growth because it raises productivity directly and permits the


adoption of newer and more efficient technologies. The


national budget with its surpluses added to the national


saving and helped to provide the margin of resources needed


for the production of large and growing volume of investment


good. Government savings also averaged above 40% of


private savings even with the annual tax reductions. This was


due to the systematic underestimation of tax revenues. The


policies to promote private investment such as accelerated


depreciation makes bankers more willing to make loans.


Therefore, the tax incentives made have had an indirect


effect on investment and growth. Finally, the simple fact that


the low tax rate in Japan may be the prevailing explanation


for the high rate of private saving and investment in Japan.


Other Determinants of Tax Structure Development and


Growth The military factor before W.W.II and after was


reduced drastically to less than 1 % of GNP. Before the


W.W.II the figure was around 28% of GNP. This is low in


international comparisons of military expenses-GNP ratio


where it is 6.3% in the USA. Japan has a low level of


welfare commitments. The average transfer payments to


national income in 1961-1970 in various countries was


20.8% in France, 7% in USA with 5% in Japan. By 1984,


the US ratio grew to 15.1% while France went up to


35.2%, in comparison with Japan’s 14%. Another factor is


the savings in Japanese thriftiness. Even at high direct


taxation on the wage earner, the average saving rate was still


between 25% and 40% GNP. This started since the Meiji


Restoration with moral suasion from the government with


slogans like "Let us avoid all luxuries so that we keep up


with the world; truly the development of our national


productive strength has its roots in reverent obedience." This


was coupled with the favorable inheritance tax laws and


capital gains law that made accumulation of wealth feasible


and worthwhile to the family centered Japanese worker.


Future of Tax System in Japan As seen in Table 5, huge


deficits arose since 1975 from the first oil shock and


accelerated due to the second one and amounted to 4.4 %


of the GNP in 1979. This has caused more alarm compared


with other countries with similar levels of debt. The


government was no longer able to cut taxes on personal


taxes and government incentive programs because of their


large losses in tax revenue were cut (Table 1). On top of the


economic repercussions, the original tax system was


repressive and unjust for the stress on simplicity. In 1989,


the Value Added Tax (VAT) was added as the consumption


indirect tax after almost ten years of debate at 3%. Reform


was necessary for between 1975 and 1984, the tax burden


rose sharply in Japan with central government taxes up by


4.1% and local taxes by 2.7% taxes. The dissatisfactions


could be categorized in the difference in tax burden among


taxpayers in which the tax ratio was "ku-ro-yon", 9-6-4 ratio


among workers, self-employed and farmers. Mismatch


between the wage system and income tax structure in which


the wages rose with seniority and taxes also increased


steeply where the middle class need it the most with the


children’s education or for a residence. Therefore the


progressiveness of the income tax for middle-class salaried


workers is too high. The unfairness in taxation on capital


income, as mentioned above is major source of savings and


investment but also is a source of inequitable tax system and


behind the massive account surpluses. The heavy corporate


tax burden which has risked dramatically since the 1970s


have caused much complaint. The outdated indirect taxes


which pose no tax on service is a failure to reflect the


changing consumption patterns. The standard procedure for


the tax reform is to reduce marginal tax rates by broadening


the tax base with the introduction of indirect consumption


taxes. It is also a cheaper and more effective way to


stimulate savings for consumption tax does not tax savings


instead of using special tax incentives. The reform is also


necessary in view of the aging population and its need for


larger social security . Tax preferences for expenses and


depreciation allowance should be reduced to reduce the loss


in tax revenue. A comprehensive tax system will not only will


achieve what Shops Mission’s real goal of tax equity but also


ensure the future mature growth of Japan for with a large


deficit, the previous tax provisions and incentives can no


longer be continued. Japan’s tax system is still midway


between a comprehensive income tax and an expenditure


tax. Change is necessary, but the role of government and


taxation still pose many hard decisions to politicians.


Bibliography 1.Ito Takatoshi., Tax Reform in Japan, The


Political Economy of Tax Reform, The Univeristy of Chicago


Press,1992 2.Ranis G., The Financing of Japanese


Development, Economic History Review April 1959 3.Allen


G.C., A Short Economic History of Modern Japan , 1962


4.Patrick H. and Rosovsky Henry., Taxation, Asia’s New


Giant, 1976 5.Ishi Hiromitsu., Ch 1-3, The Japanese Tax


System, Clarendon Press 1989 6.Ohkawa K. Ranis G.,


Economic Development in Historical Perspective, Japan and


the Developing Countries A Comparative Analysis., Basil


Blackwell, 1985 7.Dornbusch R.,. Macroeconomics – 3rd


Canadian Edition, McGraw-Hill, 1987 8.Shiraishi Takashi,


Japan’s Trade Policies 1945 to the Present Day, Athlone


Press, 1989.

Сохранить в соц. сетях:
Обсуждение:
comments powered by Disqus

Название реферата: Taxation In Japan Essay Research Paper The

Слов:4897
Символов:34020
Размер:66.45 Кб.