РефератыИностранный языкAsAsian Essay Research Paper Two years after

Asian Essay Research Paper Two years after

Asian Essay, Research Paper


Two years after the death of Mao Zedong in 1976, it became apparent


to many of China’s leaders that economic reform was necessary. During his


tenure as China’s premier, Mao had encouraged social movements such as the


Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution which had had as their bases


ideologies such as serving the people and maintaining the class struggle.


By 1978 “Chinese leaders were searching for a solution to serious economic


problems produced by Hua Guofeng, the man who had succeeded Mao Zedong as


CCP leader after Mao’s death” (Shirk 35). Hua had demonstrated a desire to


continue the ideologically based movements of Mao. Unfortunately, these


movements had left China in a state where “agriculture was stagnant,


industrial production was low, and the people’s living standards had not


increased in twenty years” (Nathan 200). This last area was particularly


troubling. While “the gross output value of industry and agriculture


increased by 810 percent and national income grew by 420 percent [between


1952 and 1980] … average individual income increased by only 100 percent”


(Ma Hong quoted in Shirk 28). However, attempts at economic reform in


China were introduced not only due to some kind of generosity on the part


of the Chinese Communist Party to increase the populace’s living standards.


It had become clear to members of the CCP that economic reform would


fulfill a political purpose as well since the party felt, properly it would


seem, that it had suffered a loss of support. As Susan L. Shirk describes


the situation in The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China,


restoring the CCP’s prestige required improving


economic performance and raising living standards.


The traumatic experience of the Cultural Revolution


had eroded popular trust in the moral and political


virtue of the CCP. The party’s leaders decided to


shift the base of party legitimacy from virtue to


competence, and to do that they had to demonstrate


that they could deliver the goods.


(23)


This movement “from virtue to competence” seemed to mark a


serious departure from orthodox Chinese political theory. Confucius


himself had posited in the fifth century BCE that those individuals who


best demonstrated what he referred to as moral force should lead the


nation. Using this principle as a guide, China had for centuries attempted


to choose at least its bureaucratic leaders by administering a test to


determine their moral force. After the Communist takeover of the country,


Mao continued this emphasis on moral force by demanding that Chinese


citizens demonstrate what he referred to as “correct consciousness.” This


correct consciousness could be exhibited, Mao believed, by the way people


lived. Needless to say, that which constituted correct consciousness was


often determined and assessed by Mao. Nevertheless, the ideal of moral


force was still a potent one in China even after the Communist takeover.


It is noteworthy that Shirk feels that the Chinese Communist


Party leaders saw economic reform as a way to regain their and their


party’s moral virtue even after Mao’s death. Thus, paradoxically, by


demonstrating their expertise in a more practical area of competence, the


leaders of the CCP felt they could demonstrate how they were serving the


people. To be sure, the move toward economic reform came about as a result


of a “changed domestic and international environment, which altered the


leadership’s perception of the factors that affect China’s national


security and social stability” (Xu 247). But Shirk feels that, in those


pre-Tienenmen days, such a move came about also as a result of an attempt


by CCP leaders to demonstrate, in a more practical and thus less obviously


ideological manner than Mao had done, their moral force.


This is not to say that the idea of economic reform was


embraced enthusiastically by all members of the leadership of the Chinese


Communist Party in 1978. To a great extent, the issue of economic reform


became politicized as the issue was used as a means by Deng Xiaoping to


attain the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party. Mao’s successor, Hua


Guofeng, had “tried to prove himself a worthy successor to Mao by draping


himself in the mantle of Maoist tradition. His approach to economic


development was orthodox Maoism with an up-to-date, international twist”


(Shirk 35). This approach was tied heavily to the development of China’s


oil reserves. “[W]hen [in 1978] estimates of the oil reserves were revised


downward[,] commitments to import plants and expand heavy industry could


not be sustained” (Shirk 35). Deng took advantage of this economic crisis


to discredit Hua and aim for leadership of the party. “Reform policies


became Deng’s platform against Hua for post-Mao leadership” (Shirk 36).


Given this history of economic reform, it is evident that “under the


present system economic questions are necessarily political questions”


(Dorn 43). Once Deng and his faction had prevailed, it was necessary for


some sort of economic reform to evolve.


The initial form the new economy took was not a radical one.


China was “still a state in which the central government retain[ed] the


dominant power in economic resource allocation and responsible local


officials work[ed] for the interest of the units under their control”


(Solinger 103). However, as time passed, some basic aspects of the old


system were altered either by design or via the process of what might be


called benign neglect. As Shirk points out, in rural areas,


decollectivization was occurring: “decision making power [was being


transferred] from collective production units (communes, brigades, and


teams) to the family” (38); purchase prices for major farm products were


increased (39). In 1985, further reforms were introduced. For example,


long-term sales contracts between farmers and the government were


established. In addition, in an effort to allow the market to determine


prices, “city prices of fruit and vegetables, fish, meat, and eggs, were


freed from government controls so they could respond to market demand”


(Shirk 39). Most importantly, “a surge of private and collective industry


and commerce in the countryside” (Shirk 39) occurred. This allowed a great


percentage of the populace to become involved in private enterprise and


investment in family or group ventures. The conditions also allowed rural


Chinese to leave the villages and become involved in industry in urban


centers (Shirk 40). The economy grew so quickly that inflation occurred


and the government had to reinstitute price controls. China’s economy


retains these characteristics of potential for growth–and inflation–to


this day.


Another important aspect of Chinese economic reform was the


decision of China to join the world economy. Deng Xiaoping and his allies


hoped to effect this 1979 resolution in two ways: by expanding foreign


trade, and by encouraging foreign companies to invest in Chinese


enterprises. This policy–denoted the “Open Policy” (Shirk 47)–was a


drastic removal from the policies of Mao Zedong and, in fact, from


centuries of Chinese political culture. The Open Policy, which designated


limited areas in China “as places with preferential conditions for foreign


investment and bases for the development of exports” (Nathan 99), was


extremely successful in the areas where it was implemented (Shirk 47).


However, it was looked upon by many Chinese as nothing less than an avenue


to “economic dependency” (Nathan 50). Indeed, when the policy was first


implemented,


many Chinese seem[ed] to fear that Deng’s policies


[were] drawing China back toward its former


semi-colonial status as a “market where the


imperialist countries dump their goods, a raw


material base, a repair and assembly workshop,


and an investment center.”


(Nathan 51)


It is interesting to note the symptoms of a national character


that would subscribe to the above sentiment. In an article written in


1981, just two years after the Open Policy was first proposed, Andrew J.


Nathan noted the almost pathological resistance to foreign intervention in


the Chinese economy: “Some Chinese fear that reliance on imported


technology will encourage a dependent psychology … [Many] Chinese


perceive joint ventures as a costly form of acquisition. ‘Some people


worry: Won’t we be suffering losses by letting foreigners make profits in


our country?’” (52). The Chinese were as vociferous about issues of


sovereignty. Nathan maintained that the Mao-led revolution, which


culminated in victory in 1949, had been fueled by “an intense patriotism:


… once China had ’stood up,’ no infringement on its sovereignty, no


matter how small, should be permitted” (53). These feelings were


manifested in denying foreign businessmen long-term, multiple entry visas,


resisting “increased foreign economic contacts” and alteration of current


ways of doing things, and disinclination to become involved in


government-to-government loans and joint ventures lest Chinese become


exploited in some way (Nathan 53-55). Given these hesitancies on the part


of the Chinese society vis-a-vis foreign relations, it is impressive that


Deng and his allies were able initially to create and implement the Open


Policy since many members of the society at large were resistant to


becoming involved in a policy so antithetical to the Chinese national


character. However, once the successes of the Open Policy were apparent,


resistance to the plan by the populace waned. Moreover, given the


confluence of politics and economics in China, it seems apparent that some


members of the CCP would also not be in favor of the plan. Nevertheless,


the Open Policy was implemented and has become instrumental in the success


of the burgeoning Chinese economy.


The implementation of the Open Policy was so successful that by


1988 the leaders of the CCP were encouraged to create a new program called


the “coastal development strategy.” In this program, even more of the


country was opened up to foreign investment–an area which, at the time,


included nearly 200 million people. Moreover, by involving more overseas


investors, “importing both capital and raw materials,” and “exporting


China’s cheap excess labor power,” the new policy was one of “‘export-led


growth’ or ‘export-oriented industrialization.’ It [was] explicitly


modeled on the experiences of Taiwan and the other Asian ’small dragons’”


(Nathan 99).


One analyst has maintained that “China now stands at the


threshold of the greatest opportunity in human history: a new economic era


promising greater wealth and achievement than any previous epoch” (Gilder


369). Illustrative of this optimistic feeling is Shanghai, an area that


was designated for preferential conditions for foreign investment and as a


base for the development of exports in 1988. This city and environs in the


Yangtze Delta area have a population of approximately 400 million people


and the city has become the nation’s financial hub for international and


national investors. For political reasons, this area was excluded from the


original Open Policy designation in 1978, but is currently in the process


of catching up with other areas so designated. Indeed, the increase in


foreign investments in the last two years is striking. The area received


3.3 billion dollars in foreign investments during the 1980s. The area


received the same amount from foreign investments in 1992 alone. In only


the first ten months of 1993, the area had received over six billion


dollars worth of foreign investments (Tyler A8).


Western analysts have asserted that the Open Policy and the


coastal development strategy have allowed Deng to entrench his political


power (Shirk 47) and will allow his power to be sustained even after death.


If this is true, Deng should be very popular in Shanghai. With its new


designation, and with the billions of foreign dollars coming into the area,


it has become necessary to improve the city’s facilities. To that end


forty billion dollars worth of public works projects have been allocated by


the central government for Shanghai within the last year (Tyler A1). These


public works projects include new sewers, a new water system, new gas


lines, a new bridge, and extensive roadwork. Future plans include the


construction of a second international airport, a container port, a new


subway system, and more roads and bridges (Tyler A8). The financial


district, which will feature a new stock exchange, is also being rebuilt by


China and foreign investors in a joint venture. By being designated for


preferential conditions, Shanghai received from the central government tax


exemptions for enterprises doing business with foreign companies, tax


holidays for new factories set up with foreign investments, and a bonded


zone–the largest in China–for duty free imports of raw materials.


Shanghai now has all the trappings of a modern city: discos, construction


projects, and conspicuous consumption. In short, where “revered monuments


and golden arches exist side by side” (Riboud 12), the appearance of the


new Shanghai does nothing less than signal “the end of the ideological


debate over China’s free market experiments” (Tyler A8).


Shanghai has joined the ranks of the modern metropolis.


However, this is not necessarily a beneficial development. Inflation is


rampant: prices have doubled in the industrial zones in the last five


years. Nevertheless, the fact that Shanghai currently possesses the fifth

r />

most expensive office space in the world demonstrates that demand is high


and that the prospects for future growth are promising (Tyler A8). Indeed,


Pudong, a free export manufacturing zone described as “the future sight of


Shanghai’s Manhattan” (Tyler A8), boasts more than twenty factories built


or being built with names like Siemens and Hitachi prominent. This area


has become particularly attractive to foreign investors and companies


because of its tax concessions, duty free imports of raw materials, and


cheap labor. Shanghai stands to benefit, too, as it receives ancillary


technology and discretionary spending from the workers and executives of


the companies represented (Tyler A8). It is conditions like these that


have caused at least one analyst to predict that China will be “the richest


economy in the world within the next 25 years” (Gilder 372).


Shanghai is by no means unique to this growth. Additional


foreign investments have continued to pour into other areas of China. For


example, the Boeing Company recently announced its intention to “invest


$100 million in a plant in [Xian] China to make tail sections for 737


jetliners” (”Boeing” D4). In addition, E.I. du Pont recently predicted


“that its investments and business in China could increase as much as ten


times by the end of the century” (”Du Pont” D2). Tellingly, du Pont’s


chairman attributed the company’s negotiations of “as many as 28 new


projects in China” to the fact “that the country’s financial changes,


improved infrastructure and rising disposable income has [sic] encouraged


the company to expand its business activities” (”Du Pont” D2).


The Chinese government has made conscientious attempts to


promote the strength of the country’s economy while protecting its


citizens. Just a few weeks ago, the government instituted “tight-money


policies, intended to control inflation and slow what has been the world’s


fastest growing major economy” (Shenon “China Halts” D1). However, after


doing so, China’s Securities Regulatory Commission was forced to stop the


issuing of new issues on the Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchanges because


the value of the markets had decreased so greatly. This latter move was


“meant to calm millions of first-time Chinese investors who evidently went


into the market believing that stock prices could only go up” (Shenon


“China Halts” D1). Might this policy show a union of economic and moral


concern? If so, it demonstrates the desire on the part of the government


to show some kind of responsibility, some moral force, to its citizenry.


At the very least, the strategy appears to show a practical desire on the


part of the government to take control over what could have been a bad


economic situation. Indeed, after these measures were instituted, China’s


trade deficit decreased (Hansell D2) and the stock markets’ volume attained


record highs (”Stocks Surge” D2). To be sure, Chinese investors remain


somewhat wary about the stock market and, ironically enough, more control


of the stock markets appears to be necessary (Shenon “A Nail-Biting” D1).


But, in discussing Chinese attempts to control inflation, Philip J. Suttle,


head of emerging markets research at the investment firm of J.P. Morgan,


has predicted that “[i]t looks as though the Chinese are going to have the


soft landing they are aiming for” (quoted in Hansell D2).


China’s interest in stock markets is no longer restricted to


within its own boundaries. This month, Shandong Huaneng Power Development


Company, “the first mainland Chinese company to have its primary listing on


the New York Stock Exchange” (”China Stock” D5), began trading shares. The


stock should be an attractive one to investors: Chinese electrical “demand


… is expected to grow by a whopping 17 million kilowatts a year until the


turn of the century” (Zuckerman D6). Moreover, China stands to gain from


the issue’s sales. “The company plans to use the $311 million dollars it


received from the offering to retire $83 million in loans from … Chinese


state entities. It also plans to expand its overall generating capacity”


(Zuckerman D6). Nor does this signify the only Chinese attempt of raising


capital from foreign sources on foreign soil. “Three more power companies


are expected to be listed in New York and Hong Kong in the coming months”


(Zuckerman D6).


Given the apparent strength of the Chinese economy as shown by


huge public works projects, extensive foreign investments, participation in


the world economy, and a generally higher standard of living by the


populace, it would appear that China is now ready to join the world as a


modern capitalistic and democratic society. However, this is not quite the


case. The CCP retains vestiges of those characteristics of insularity and


intransigence as discussed by Nathan. Because of its human rights record,


the country’s economic growth is being impeded. That is, the politics of


China, which have always been allied with its economics, are now


restricting international growth.


The United States, especially, has been concerned with China’s


treatment of political dissidents. In May, President Clinton decided to


end linking China’s trade status with the United States with its record on


human rights. The president has been criticized for this because of


situations like the following: trials for “‘counterrevolutionary


activities’ [including] … plans to use a remote-controlled airplane to


drop pro-democracy leaflets over … Tienenmen Square” (”China cracks” A13)


have recently begun for fifteen dissidents and labor organizers who were


involved in the Tienenmen Square protests. These trials have “been delayed


twice, first to avoid negative international reaction just before the


decision last September on China’s failed bid to host the 2000 Olympics and


then this spring to avoid influencing Clinton’s trade decision” (”China


cracks” A13). In addition, China has instituted “new laws effective in


June [which] give sweeping powers to China’s State Security Bureau to clamp


down on dissidents” (”China cracks” A13). China is fully aware of United


States’ concerns about its human rights record. Given the fact that the


United States has made it clear to China that that record will be allied


with trade status, China’s timing of such restrictive activities has caused


United States legislators and administrators to question China’s sincerity


in its desire to have a favored trade status with the United States.


Indeed, just in the past few days, it took a


last-minute lobbying campaign by President Clinton


and his Cabinet [to head off a] potentially


embarrassing vote by the House of Representatives to


restrict trade with China as a way to punish Beijing


for reported human rights violations.


(Bradsher A7)


But China’s problems in joining the community of the world


market have more to do than with its political ethos and practices. China


appears not to understand or to be able to follow through on fundamental


modern economic practices. For example, the United States has recently


complained that “China has not complied with international rules on access


to its markets and protection of copyrights and patents” (Gargan 14). Such


non-compliance could make it difficult for China to become a founding


member of the


World Trade Organization, the successor to the


General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and the body


that is intended to promote global free trade by


lowering tariffs and other barriers, [which] will


be formally constituted on January 1, 1994.


(Gargan 14)


The specific nature of the United States’ complaint has to do with China’s


pirating of musical compact disks, video laser disks and computer software.


In fact, it is estimated that such pirating costs American companies a


billion dollars a year. This phenomenon seems to have to do with the


Chinese psychology as described by Nathan. In his 1981 essay he noted that


China did not wish to become a “technological client of the west. The


preferred solution is to buy one item and copy it” (Nathan 52). Clearly,


this is not the way trade works today. It is the United States’ position


that China must adhere to the rules of trade before it can be included in a


trade organization. Needless to say, exclusion from WTO would be


disastrous for any country, but particularly for an emerging market such as


China.


Even on a day to day basis, China’s economic leaders seem


unable to understand how some aspects of a market economy work. In


discussing the status of the Shanghai Stock Market, for example, one stock


dealer referred to it as “crazy” (”Stocks Surge” D2). Moreover, American


analysts have been amazed to discover in the Shanghai market “the lack of


regulation and the poor disclosure requirements. Some companies have been


listed for two or three years and have not issued an annual report”


(Hansell D2). It is no wonder that Chinese investors become anxious about


their investments.


The issuance of shares in the Shandong Huaneng Power


Development Company also demonstrates the lack of expertise on the part of


the Chinese in the modern world market. In fact, according to one Hong


Kong investment analyst, “‘[t]he company wasn’t really a company. It was


just a bunch of discrete plants that they tied a bow around and wrote a


prospectus on’” (Zuckerman D6). The prospectus guaranteed a fifteen


percent annual return on investments. In fact, the return will no doubt be


less than that because of prevailing currency exchange rates and debt that


the company will have to assume.


To be sure, the problems of the Shandong Huaneng Power


Development Company and the Shanghai Stock Exchange may demonstrate only


the problems of an immature economy. Nevertheless, if China wishes to


become a viable member of the world economic community, such shortcomings


will have to be eliminated quickly.


These apparent problems may also be the result of an economic


system that is run by the state. Certainly, one thing that the CCP has


attempted to do is create a market economy while retaining a state


controlled system. This structure may be possible but it does have its


critics. Steven N.S. Cheung, in an essay written in 1989, argued for the


“creation of private property by mandate” (31), feeling that privatization


in China would lead to necessary additional investment in the society’s


infrastructure and the establishment of a “judicial system that is based


firmly on the principle of equality before the law” (Cheung 32). Echoing


Cheung’s sentiments, James Dorn saw problems in the areas of Chinese


banking and finance. In this arrangement, Dorn argued, “the state controls


the bulk of investment resources. The lack of a private capital market has


handicapped economic development in China and hampered rational investment


decisionmaking” (43). In order to become a modern economic state Dorn


argued for the necessity of circumventing “China’s ruling elite who oppose


the dismantling of state monopolies and who benefit from price fixing and


nonprice rationing” (51). Xu Zhiming also saw the necessity for a


revamping of the Chinese system: “We must throw off the traditional system


completely” (249) in order for economic reform to thrive.


Communist Party members, of course, articulate a different


position. In a recent interview that appeared in the Beijing Review, Feng


Bing, Deputy Secretary General of the State Commission for Restructuring


the Economic System, spoke to the issue of economic reform in China. It is


striking that Feng spoke of the benefits that the populace has received as


a result of the economic reform now occurring in China. That is, his


comments appeared to demonstrate the beneficence, or the moral force, of


the Chinese Communist Party vis-a-vis economic reform. He noted that such


reform involves the essence of socialism: “to liberate and develop


productive forces; to eradicate exploitation; to remove polarization; and


… to attain the goal of common prosperity” (”Official” 12). Thus, CCP


leaders still appear to see their roles as representatives of a moral


force. CCP members and leaders wish economic reform not to be judged on


just its practical merits, but also as an effect of the moral force of the


leadership. Economic reform, then, becomes nothing less than a moral


crusade and it is thus easy to see why, for example, China “has staked its


national prestige on becoming a founding member of the World Trade


Organization” (Gargan 14).


Will China succeed in taking its place among the nations of the


world market? Will the CCP succeed in retaining its political power given


the drastic changes in the societal makeup of China that are occurring due


to the changing economic realities? I would suggest that the chances are


better for the former than for the latter. Once the Chinese attain more


sophistication relative to international and national markets, institute a


more manageable banking system, and make a good faith effort to insure


acceptable human rights, the country may well become “the richest economy


in the world within the next 25 years” (Gilder 372). However, whether or


not these conditions can occur without a weakening of the state controlled


system is problematic. The most impressive and far-reaching display of


moral force by the CCP may well have to be a voluntary reduction of its


power over the people. Paradoxically, by weakening itself politically, the


party may demonstrate its true moral force by liberating, politically and


economically, one billion Chinese citizens.

Сохранить в соц. сетях:
Обсуждение:
comments powered by Disqus

Название реферата: Asian Essay Research Paper Two years after

Слов:4684
Символов:32435
Размер:63.35 Кб.